864¹ø : À̹øÁÖ ÀÌÄÚ³ë¹Ì½ºÆ® ±â»ç¸¦ º¸´Ù ¹ÎÀÇ·Ã »ý°¢ÀÌ ³ª¼ ±â»ç ¿Ã¸³´Ï´Ù. |
±Û¾´ÀÌ: Àº³ª |
µî·Ï: 2002-12-25 07:08:14 |
Á¶È¸: 203 |
PILL PAUPERS
How to get cheaper drugs for poor countries
IT HAS been another week of long arguments at the World Trade
Organisation over how to implement last year's Doha agreement on getting
cheaper drugs for poor countries. The main dispute has been over how far
to extend compulsory licensing, a tool that confers the right to
manufacture patented drugs without the patent-holder's consent. Because
America is holding out for a narrow ambit for any new provisions on
compulsory licensing, restricting them to drugs for such diseases as
AIDS, malaria and tuberculosis, it looks unlikely that a deal will be
struck by the original target date of the end of this year. Yet even if
agreement is reached at the eleventh hour, the entire argument misses a
bigger point: that this is not the right long-term solution to the
problem of getting cheaper drugs to poor countries.
Few of the world's poorest countries are in any position to use
compulsory licensing as it stands. Because they lack not only the
administrative and legal capacity but also any domestic drug industry to
exploit it, they instead import generic drugs from countries such as
India, which has a thriving trade in copycat drugs because it is not yet
obliged to recognise patents. This will end by 2006, when India and most
other developing countries have agreed to enforce drug patents.
Even if this is got round through expanded new provisions on compulsory
licensing, generic manufacturers in India and elsewhere may no longer be
prepared to invest in producing knock-offs of new drugs only for Africa
and other poor places, when their more lucrative home markets are no
longer open to cheap copies. Worse still, fears of compulsory licensing
are sure to reduce the incentives for big drug firms to do research into
cures for many of the diseases that most afflict poor countries. If they
know that the profits from any drug they find will immediately be
whittled away through compulsory licensing, they will be even less
likely than they are now to look for the drugs in the first place.
There are better ways than compulsory licensing of balancing the
interests of patients in poor countries with the need to maintain
incentives for continued investment and development of new medicines.
One idea, favoured by European governments, is differential pricing,
under which drug firms would be urged to charge different prices in
different markets, based on some measure of need and purchasing power.
There have been attempts to introduce deeply discounted pricing for poor
countries, but these are small efforts, restricted to a handful of anti-
retroviral and anti-malarial medicines.
There are also two big problems that may stop differential pricing going
much further. One is that drug companies worry about the risk of drugs
that they sell cheaply in poor countries making their way back to rich-
country markets. A second is that governments could exploit the fact
that companies are selling drugs more cheaply in developing countries as
an excuse to press firms to cut their prices at home. The result of
either would be that drug companies might see their profits in rich-
country markets undermined by their sales of drugs at cheaper prices in
poor countries.
The ideal solution would be to stop searching for ingenious ways to get
drug companies to bear the costs of selling essential drugs more cheaply
to poor countries. Instead, rich-country governments, which have
recognised the moral and economic imperative to enable poor countries to
afford such drugs, should put up the necessary cash. They will have to
be prepared to pay full prices, set high enough to ensure that drug
companies have an incentive to develop new medicines, including those
for typical poor-country ailments. That would be expensive, certainly:
but it would be a better use of overseas-aid budgets than any number of
white-elephant infrastructure projects.
|
|
|